A week later and everyone is a bit more
nervous, with the speculation that US sovereign debt purchases by the
Federal Reserve will wind down and with the Bank of Japan completely
cornered.
In anticipation to the debate on the Fed’s bond purchase tapering, on April 28th (see here)
I wrote why the Federal Reserve cannot exit Quantitative Easing: Any
tightening must be preceded by a change in policy that addresses fiscal
deficits. It has absolutely nothing to do with unemployment or activity
levels. Furthermore, it will require international coordination. This is
also not possible. The Bank of Japan is helplessly facing the collapse
of the country’s sovereign debt, the European Monetary Union is anything
but what its name indicates, with one of its members under capital
controls, and China is improvising as its credit bubble bursts.
In light of this, we are now beginning
to see research that incorporates the problem of future higher inflation
to the valuation of different asset classes. One example of this, in
the corporate credit space was Morgan Stanley’s “Credit Continuum: Debt Cost and the Real Deal” published on May 17th,
2013. Upon reading it, I was uncomfortable with the notion that
inflation is the simple reflection of the change in a price index, which
implies the thesis of the neutrality of money. For instance, the said
research note discusses how standard financial metrics compare vis-à-vis
a rate of inflation.
Why is this relevant? The gap between
current valuations in the capital markets (both debt and credit) and the
weak activity data releases could mistakenly be interpreted as a
reflection of the collective expectation of an imminent recovery. The
question therefore is: Can inflation bring a recovery? Can inflation
positively affect valuations?
I am not going to comment on others’
views or recommendations, but on the underlying method. A price index is
a mental tool that has no relation to reality. In the real world, we
trade driven by relative prices. To infer economic behaviour off changes
in a price index is a mistake. The impact of inflation is more complex.
For this reason and in anticipation of future debates on this topic, I
offer you today a microeconomic analysis of such impact, on value.
Framework
I suggest that a good way (but certainly
not the only one) to assess the impact of inflation on the valuation of
a firm is to think of the same within the typical free-cash flow
approach. After all, what matters is not how inflation can
affect a certain component of its capital structure, but how the entire
value of a firm is impacted, before the same can be shared among the
different contributors to the said capital structure (i.e. equity, debt
holders, etc.)
Simplifying, as far as I can recall from
the times when I worked in the area of Private Equity, the way to
calculate the free cash flow of a firm for a determined period is to
obtain its operating margin, add to it depreciation & amortization
costs and subtract capital expenditures, changes in net working capital
and taxes. I show the formula below:
Revenues– Operating Costs
Operating margin
+ Depreciation & Amortization
- Capital Expenditures
- Change in net working capital
- Operating tax
Free Cash flow
Analysis
What follows is a discussion on the impact of inflation on each of the components of the valuation formula above:
Revenues (= unit price x volume sold)
Under inflation, only those firms that
have pricing power can defend the value of their production. At the same
time and because inflation brings unemployment and the destruction of
purchasing power, in general (not for all firms, of course), sales
volume drops too. This backdrop encourages consolidation, where big
players get bigger and small ones disappear. With it, the bigger firms
obtain oligopolistic to monopolistic pricing power which assures two
things: The currency zone where this development takes place loses in
innovation and prices become less flexible. This inflexibility, when
fully unfolded, directly leads to indexation, which is the stepping
stone for any hyperinflationary process. If the consolidating firms are
public, it is likely that during the consolidation process they become
private via leveraged deals, as long as credit is still available.
Operating costs (=unit cost x volume bought + factors)
With regards to direct inputs, the same
pricing problem described above arises. There are those firms that have
leverage with their suppliers and can force these to delay price
increases (i.e. margin contraction) and those that can’t. Consolidation
therefore pays off on this front too, carrying the same consequences
mentioned above. From an accounting perspective, when inflation is high,
firms can’t even measure the cost of their inputs and are forced to
take a Schrodinger approach, with either Last in-First Out (LIFO) or First in – First Out (FIFO) accounting.
With regards to indirect inputs, these
can be segmented into labour and capital. Labour intensive firms will
struggle with a unionizing work force and inflation always nourishes the
growth of unions, to renegotiate labour contracts. All things equal,
this context simultaneously encourages higher unemployment and illegal
immigration, because while credit is available at negative real rates
(i.e. the nominal interest rate is lower than the inflation rate), firms
will find more convenient to replace labour with capital. This takes
place during the lower stages of an inflationary process. In later
stages, credit disappears and the higher interest rates make refinancing
debts unfeasible, bankrupting those firms that dared to invest in
capital expenditures.
Where the required labour is low skilled but expensive due to social
security legislation, firms will also replace it with illegal
immigration, whenever possible.Conclusion
The impact of inflation on operating margins (i.e. revenues – operating costs) is to drive consolidation, the replacement of labour by capital, indexation, price rigidity and the loss of competitiveness. The loss of competitiveness is the natural result of an environment that favours oligopolistic/monopolistic structures and short-term investment opportunities. It is very common to blame entrepreneurs or management for this outcome. However, the conditions that drive firms to adopt these survival strategies are the exclusive responsibility of politicians.
Depreciation & Amortization
“…Both depreciation and amortization
(as well as depletion) are methods used to prorate the cost of a
specific type of asset to the asset’s life…these methods are calculated
by subtracting the asset’s salvage value from its original cost…” (Investopedia)
It is clear that any attempt to
accurately portray the value and life cycle of fixed or intangible
assets under inflation becomes irrelevant. What if due to high inflation
the salvage value of an asset is higher than its original cost?
Under inflation there is uncertainty on
the true cost of maintaining the fixed resources involved in the
operation of a business. This uncertainty forces firms to cut back on
capital expenditures. Investment demand and economic growth therefore
collapse
Capital expenditures
Because nothing can be reasonably
forecasted under inflation and growth and efficiencies are better served
via consolidation and without innovation, capital expenditures can only
be of a very short nature, if any.
Change in net working capital
This item is perhaps the most neglected
and yet, most relevant, in my view. For valuation purposes, an increase
in net working capital means that a higher amount of capital is tied to
the operations of a firm. Therefore, a lower amount of cash is available
to the contributors of capital to the firm (i.e. debt and equity
holders). For this reason, the change in net working capital is
subtracted in the valuation formula above.
What is net working capital? In simple terms:
Accounts receivable
+ Inventory
- Accounts payable
Net working capital
If from one period to another the time necessary to collect on accounts receivable increase and/or the inventory turnover
necessary to run an operation decreases, the value of the firm falls,
as less cash is available to the contributors of capital. Alternatively,
if the firm manages to increase the time necessary to honor accounts
payable –all things equal- more cash is available.
What is the impact of inflation on net
working capital? Complete! Under inflation, firms seek to delay any cash
outflow. The higher their accounts payable, the more debt they dilute.
At the same time, bank lending quickly shrinks. At high inflation
levels, even working capital lending disappears. At this stage, vendor
financing is key and only those companies that demonstrate a steady
commitment to their suppliers can obtain credit from them. Suppliers, on
the other side, often go bankrupt precisely because they cannot collect
on their receivables. One of the painful ironies of inflation is that under it, liquidity evaporates!
With regards to inventory, this is
counter intuitive, but firms will try to maximize its amount, as long as
they can get vendor financing. The accumulation of inventory allows firms to lock in a cost of production that would otherwise be uncertain. This is very inefficient. Just-in-time production models become totally unfeasible. The accumulation of
inventory is more understandable when one realizes that inflation
is the destruction of the medium of indirect exchange, which forces us
to barter. Under barter, inventory is not a burden.
Just as much as firms seek to delay cash
outflows, they will want to collect as quickly as possible. Those firms
that operate at the end of the distribution chain and can sell to a
granular, cash-paying public will be at an advantage over those that
operate at earlier links of the chain (and have a concentrated customer
base which demands vendor financing). Inflation therefore leads to
consolidation on this basis too, towards the end of a distribution chain.
An example of a firm that would fit this
profile, benefitting from an inflationary context would be Costco
Wholesale Corp. (and no, this is not
an investment recommendation, but a hypothetical example). As Costco
sells in bulk, its customer base would grow, since the public that seeks
to escape from a devaluing currency and lock the price of necessary
staples would see an advantage in purchasing the same in quantities, at a
discount. Simultaneously, the company would be in a privileged position
to exert pricing power over its suppliers and grow via acquisitions. As
an extreme (but
illustrative) example, I recall that during the ‘80s in Argentina, when
employees were paid their salaries, many took the day off (and parents
left their kids with nannies) to go shopping. They were simply ensuring
that not one day would pass with them holding depreciating currency,
which had to be exchanged as fast as possible for all the goods that
were going to be consumed until the next wage payment. They set off in a
hurry and bought, when possible, in bulk!
Operating tax
Tax payments are simply one more cash
outflow. Even without inflation, one tries to minimize and delay this
outflow. Under high inflation, delaying its payment is a matter of
survival and represents and additional source of
financing. Because all hyperinflations
took place before the internet era, we don’t know how easy it will be to
delay tax payments when the next hyperinflation arrives. I imagine it
will be much harder in the digital era.
Conclusions
The inflationary policies carried out
globally today, if successful will have a considerably negative impact
on economic growth. The microeconomic impact described above brings the
following unintended and unnecessary macroeconomic consequences:
-Oligopolistic/ Monopolistic structures-Loss of innovation, competitiveness
-Indexation, price rigidities
-Unionization of labour force and higher unemployment
-Illegal migratory flows
-Destruction of public capital markets
-Higher fiscal deficits
If this analysis is correct, the record
asset values we see today cannot be interpreted as the omen of an
imminent recovery. I am not saying that these nominal
values are not justified. What I am saying is that they should not be
interpreted as an indication that economic growth is on the way □
Martin Sibileau
No comments:
Post a Comment